Serious investment thinking that doesn’t take itself too seriously.

HOME

LOGIN

ABOUT THE CURIOUS INVESTOR GROUP

SUBSCRIBE

SIGN UP TO THE WEEKLY

PARTNERS

TESTIMONIALS

CONTRIBUTORS

CONTACT US

MAGAZINE ARCHIVE

PRIVACY POLICY

SEARCH

-- CATEGORIES --

GREEN CHRONICLE

PODCASTS

THE AGENT

ALTERNATIVE ASSETS

THE ANALYST

THE ARCHITECT

ASTROPHYSIST

THE AUCTIONEER

THE ECONOMIST

EDITORIAL NOTES

FACE TO FACE

THE FARMER

THE FUND MANAGER

THE GUEST ESSAY

THE HEAD HUNTER

HEAD OF RESEARCH

THE HISTORIAN

INVESTORS NOTEBOOK

THE MACRO VIEW

POLITICAL INSIDER

THE PROFESSOR

PROP NOTES

RESIDENTIAL INVESTOR

TECHNOLOGY

UNCORKED

An illiquid housing market is holding Britain back

by | Aug 1, 2018

The Analyst

An illiquid housing market is holding Britain back

by | Aug 1, 2018

It’s amazing the capacity some policy wonks have to identify a problem and then come up with a completely wrongheaded solution.

So it is with the latest report from the Housing and Finance Institute. The authors insist that rather than cutting stamp duty, the Government should be subsidising people to buy houses. Their argument is that private renting introduces uncertainty into family life, therefore we should have less of that, thank you very much.

In fairness, the report does acknowledge one of the great truths of the housing market – that it’s linked to the unemployment level. This has been pointed out for both the UK and US markets. Whisper it quietly, but it is actually possible for the home ownership rate to be too high. The logic is that as economies change, jobs are relocated and people need to be able to move home to take up work elsewhere. In a society where most people are owner occupiers, that can become a very expensive matter.

High home ownership can mean lower labour mobility and a higher unemployment rate than there might otherwise be. It follows that having a thriving rental sector, one that is more liquid, means the unemployment rate is lower. Nor will increasing the amount of social housing improve things. Mobility among social renters is actually even worse than among owner occupiers, as it’s near impossible to gain social housing outside the local authority one is already in. Too much social housing therefore contributes to unemployment.

So the Housing and Finance Institute are right to note that too much ownership affects employment and that labour mobility has fallen this past couple of decades. They are also right that the private rental market has hugely expanded.  But they then conclude that this means private rental is no longer important when it comes to employment, so we can throw money at subsidising home ownership. You know, to reduce that uncertainty affecting family life. This is missing a hugely important point – we’ve recently had the Mother of all Recessions. Recessions are a time when labour mobility across jobs drops.

In fact, we rather read our economic runes the other way around: when more people are willing to quit one job for another – possibly moving around the country to do so – it suggests the labour market is recovering from its recession-induced torpor.

But there’s a much more important factor weighing on the British housing market — the huge hikes in stamp duty overseen first by Gordon Brown and then continued under George Osborne. If we think of labour mobility in terms of liquidity,  private rentals are the most liquid, then owner occupation, with social and council housing a distant third. They contribute to the unemployment rate in that order.

But in terms of portions of the market, owner occupation is much the most important, constituting well over 60 per cent of the entire market. And governments of both stripes have contrived to introduced a significant tax wedge into that liquidity. If we’re going to maintain a high level of stamp duty, we might in fact argue that private rentals should expand further to counteract the negative employment effects of a bunged up housing market.

There’s an altogether more sensible approach, of course. Given everyone agrees that labour mobility has an impact upon the unemployment rate, there is a strong case for reducing stamp duty back to what it ought to be, a fee for the state’s services in registering property. By doing so the Government would go some way to making it easier for people to buy and sell. After all, optimal tax theory is clear that we shouldn’t be taxing transactions but consumption, or at a pinch, income.

Lowering stamp duty would also remove the need for subsidising house purchases. As in so many cases with public policy, the answer lies not in ever more government intervention, but in the state taking a step back and letting the market do its work. The best thing the Government can do here is less of what it is currently doing, namely taxing property transactions, reducing labour mobility and increasing the equilibrium unemployment rate as a result.

Of course there are government solutions to problems, but nearly all of them involve the government doing less of the foolish things it currently does.

Article originally published by CapX. 

About Tim Worstall

About Tim Worstall

Tim Worstall is Senior Fellow at the Adam Smith Institute.

INVESTOR'S NOTEBOOK

Smart people from around the world share their thoughts

READ MORE >

THE MACRO VIEW

Recent financial news and how it connects across all asset classes

READ MORE >

TECHNOLOGY

Fintech, proptech and what it all means

READ MORE >

PODCASTS

Engaging conversations with strategic thinkers

READ MORE >

THE ARCHITECT

Some of the profession’s best minds

READ MORE >

RESIDENTIAL ADVISOR

Making money from residential property investment

READ MORE >

THE PROFESSOR

Analysis and opinion from the academic sphere

READ MORE >

FACE-TO-FACE

In-depth interviews with leading figures in the real estate/investment world.

READ MORE >