Serious investment thinking that doesn’t take itself too seriously.

HOME

LOGIN

ABOUT THE CURIOUS INVESTOR GROUP

SUBSCRIBE

SIGN UP TO THE WEEKLY

PARTNERS

TESTIMONIALS

CONTRIBUTORS

CONTACT US

MAGAZINE ARCHIVE

PRIVACY POLICY

SEARCH

-- CATEGORIES --

GREEN CHRONICLE

PODCASTS

THE AGENT

ALTERNATIVE ASSETS

THE ANALYST

THE ARCHITECT

ASTROPHYSIST

THE AUCTIONEER

THE ECONOMIST

EDITORIAL NOTES

FACE TO FACE

THE FARMER

THE FUND MANAGER

THE GUEST ESSAY

THE HEAD HUNTER

HEAD OF RESEARCH

THE HISTORIAN

INVESTORS NOTEBOOK

THE MACRO VIEW

POLITICAL INSIDER

THE PROFESSOR

PROP NOTES

RESIDENTIAL INVESTOR

TECHNOLOGY

UNCORKED

The strange business of modern farming

by | Aug 7, 2019

The Farmer

The strange business of modern farming

by | Aug 7, 2019

Farms are peculiar assets. Returns are undeniable – but inaccessible. And subsidies, it seems, only make things worse.

Farms are capital-intensive businesses, with land, buildings, fixed equipment, working capital for labour, livestock, seeds, fertiliser – almost all of which needs to be expensed before a penny of income is received. For permanent crops, an income stream may be years into the future. 

Much of that capital is locked up in assets for a very long time; and farmers never seem to generate quite enough income from their investment (or at least not enough to cover all their personal demands, let alone the re-investment needs of the asset). Farmers frequently understate their working capital needs (which also grow over time) – the world has plenty of providers of short-term debt to farmers. But farmers are also endlessly surprised at the relentless appearance of cash on retirement/sale, as machinery and crops are sold and the inputs for the next crops are not bought.

Farms are peculiar assets – part real estate, part commodity play (long only!), part operational with variable working capital needs, and with one unique characteristic which sets them apart: they are appreciating assets. To use a real estate analogy, farm productivity growth is as if you owned an office block with 100 floors, and a new floor appeared at very little or no cost every year. 

And yet they are assets which are seen by many, and certainly by many farmers, as delivering (very) poor returns on capital. 

Here is the conundrum. Over time (and this is more visible at an industry level than for individual farms), farms both produce more per hectare or per animal and do so with greater efficiency (reducing unit cost of production). These productivity gains fall to the bottom line and are then capitalised into the value of the farm. 

This capital growth is a key component of returns, but, of course, is not cash in the hands of the farmer – and often not recognised as a return at all.

At the same time that the farmer is generating an apparently inadequate return, there are a wide range of draws on that modest farm income – inter-generational family funding (retirement and education), re-investment in efficient production systems, replacement of assets, and adequate rewards for labour. And all of this has to come from an uncertain income, driven by factors beyond the control of the farmer – the weather and global commodity markets, where one man’s disaster is another’s bonanza. 

The bonanza year often ends up off-farm (skiing chalet etc.), as a reward for hard work. Yet if there is not enough reinvestment, there is a drift into higher unit costs of production at the farm level, even as the industry as a whole is improving; income falls, the ability to re-invest erodes, and the farm enters a vicious spiral of lack of competitiveness – which can no longer be corrected. 

This uncertain and volatile cash return on a capital-intensive asset, growing in value over time but from which that value growth is often inaccessible, and the relatively small size of most farms, renders them structurally vulnerable and lacking in capital resilience. With the secure supply of food a political imperative, it is then all too easy to fall prey to the subsidy safety net.

Receipt of farm subsidies does much more than keep the farmer safe from uncertainty and address a lack of wider resilience. The annual value of the payment is also immediately capitalised into the land – and at a very low cap rate, as it is effectively a government bond. So while the cash income might have increased with the subsidy, the total return might actually have gone down, with a higher proportion now attributable to the increase in land value. Research by a German institution has found that the return to farmland in countries like New Zealand and Australia, where there are no subsidies, is shared about 50:50 between capital growth and operating income. For countries with farm subsidies, the split is closer to 70:30 in favour of capital growth. 

No wonder farmers complain that they can’t live off their income, and can’t expand their businesses on the back of net cash flow. Their short-term safety net is also their long-term noose.

Small in size, vulnerable to factors beyond their control, with substantial lock-up of capital returning a modest and variable cash income, it begs the question about the most appropriate capital structure for the industry. Farms are long-term capital assets, in need of certainty and resilience; but they face very short-term volatility, particularly at the asset level, and need an aligned and well-incentivised management making the multitude of daily decisions. Owner occupation puts all the competing interests under one hat, but does not address the tension between short-term cash needs and long-term asset appreciation. The landlord/tenant structure is damagingly mis-aligned, and ultimately has its origins in feudal obligations.

The possibility of Brexit has given British farmers, farming representatives and policy makers the unusual (unexpected?) opportunity to take a long hard look at the industry. To date the great majority have failed to do so, focusing instead on the short term, the parochial and their own particular vested interests. The Secretary of State spoke at the 2018 Oxford Farming Conference about the unintended outcomes and negative impact of farm subsidies on the industry… and then went on to talk about how he would introduce a whole new raft of subsidies post-Brexit to replace the CAP.

In the end (and the end may be a long time coming) subsidies are no substitute for competitive efficiency, innovation and entrepreneurial talent. The extraordinary lag in productivity growth in British farming is indicative of a problem. I grew up in the West Highlands of Scotland, where my father tried to persuade sheep and cattle to grow fat on a diet of rock and bog. On such unforgiving land, he was, as I see now, remarkably successful – but, when he retired in 1987, nobody continued farming that land. It no longer made sense to do so, despite the tidal wave of government support.

About Nick Tapp

About Nick Tapp

Nick has spent a career in farming and the food supply chain, developing a particular interest in the perversity of politics as it effects much of the industry. Nick Tapp is Chairman of Craigmore.

INVESTOR'S NOTEBOOK

Smart people from around the world share their thoughts

READ MORE >

THE MACRO VIEW

Recent financial news and how it connects across all asset classes

READ MORE >

TECHNOLOGY

Fintech, proptech and what it all means

READ MORE >

PODCASTS

Engaging conversations with strategic thinkers

READ MORE >

THE ARCHITECT

Some of the profession’s best minds

READ MORE >

RESIDENTIAL ADVISOR

Making money from residential property investment

READ MORE >

THE PROFESSOR

Analysis and opinion from the academic sphere

READ MORE >

FACE-TO-FACE

In-depth interviews with leading figures in the real estate/investment world.

READ MORE >